Stephanie Hurder is the Founding Economist and Partner at Prysm Group. She’s also a CoinDesk columnist and an academic contributor to the World Economic Forum. In this podcast she joins us to discuss a recent article she published in CoinDesk entitled “Why Enterprise Blockchains Fail: No Economic Incentives”.

 

What is blockchain?

Blockchain is a type of distributed ledger. A ledger is a database, which is usually maintained by a single organisation like a bank to track the ins and outs of our bank account. The bank is responsible for maintaining and updating that ledger.

A distributed ledger is a shared ledger where multiple different stakeholders, such as banks or insurance companies, collectively control and update the ledger. They have a process called the consensus process, where in order to make a change or an update to this shared database, there needs to be a certain level of agreement among the different stakeholders. This ensures that not a single organisation or entity controls this shared database.

Blockchain is a particular type of shared ledger in which though the transactions or the updates to the shared ledger are processed in blocks. Smart contracts is a feature that often is associated with blockchain.

 

Enterprise blockchain is in the doldrums

On the 2nd of March 2020 Stephanie published an article on CoinDesk entitled “Why Enterprise Blockchains Fail: No Economic Incentives”. In the article she stated why “Enterprise blockchain is in the doldrums”.

As an active participant working in many different blockchain projects Stephanie noticed a familiar patern where numerous enterprise blockchain initiatives, often established by consortia, would announce that they have a proof of concept or that they’re going to do a pilot for a specific use case. But then a year later many of those pilots would either fail to launch or wouldn’t work.

Blockchain has the ability to deliver a lot of economic value to consortia and groups using it to solve business problems. However, it is very important for all the parties to be very clear about what is driving the value creation and who benefits from it and how that value is being distributed. Without a clear understanding of that, it becomes very difficult to set up the necessary infrastructure for a successful project.

 

Blockchain platforms as economic systems

Blockchain consortia are established to create economic value either to help companies save money, allow for synergies, or generate new revenue opportunities. There’s an economic rationale for almost every blockchain project. Members of the consortia have to agree on who are the different stakeholders, their incentives to join and how is value create and distributed.

Stephanie notes that too many blockchain projects take a technology first approach instead of an economic one.

 

Value creation in a blockchain project

In a blockchain based consortium, value creation can be looked at in terms of three layers;

  1. Value from the features of DLT
  2. Role of network effects
  3. Synergies – value, cost and network

 

Value from the features of DLT

The first layer is what is the value that the features of distributed ledger or the blockchain is, that it bringing itself.

The Prysm Group has a framework called the 3 C’s: coordination, commitment and control. The different features of a distributed ledger or blockchain create these levers of value depending on the different use cases.

Stephanie gives the example of a use case with smart contracts. One of the big economic frictions is with regards contract certainty. How difficult it is to monitor and enforce contracts. One of the promises of enabling smart contracts is that whenever the conditions of the contract are met the contract automatically executes it. This creates value in the form of commitment.

The second layer is the network effect. As the number of participants and type of participants grow the value to the network is going to increase.

Finally, when a network is running different types of applications on the same chain you start to have synergies in terms of value, cost and network. For example, you can have the same source of contribution of data being used in many different places and applications.

 

Network effects

When looking at network effects what is really important to identify is, which ones are going to deliver more value when the network is young and new versus when it’s more mature.

Blockchain consortiums are typically launched by an initial group of founding members who hope that the consortium will succeed and grow by attracting new members to it. In many use cases the belief is that they will generate most of their value when the network is big and robust but not necessarily as much at the beginning of the network.

A key point to make is that having a large founding member at the onset doesn’t guarantee success of the consortium or the network effect. In some cases it can even stifle it.

 

Bilateral and multilateral use cases and transactions

The question is how do you organise and stage your network effects and products?

To answer that question, Stephanie uses a hypothetical example of a consortium of medical providers and insurance companies that are forming a consortium for data sharing in the health space. Some potential use cases and application are bilateral transactions. For example, such a use case is where a doctor needs to check whether or not a patient is enrolled with a single insurance company. An example of a multilateral transaction is where one insurance company wants to share data with 10 other insurance companies.

Typically, a new blockchain consortia will have bilateral use cases with bilateral transaction as they deliver more value early on. Multilateral transactions need more participants on board the network which takes more time to reach.

 

Global vs local network effects

Another dimension to analyse when looking at network effects is global vs local. A global network effect is one where the quantity of people or the fraction of a total industry is using the network.  An example of this is eBay. If you’re looking to buy vintage teacups it doesn’t necessarily matter if the buyer knows the seller, all that matters is that they have access to a large number of reputable sellers on eBay.

Social networks are the opposite where little use is derived from joining a large network if none of the people you’re connected to in real life aren’t on the social network. Social networks are local network effects.

Consequently, when launching a blockchain consortium it is important to know who the initial users of the network will be to grow the network, will it be a global or a local one?

 

Synergies – value, cost and network

There are typically three types of synergies in a blockchain consortium;

  • Value creation synergy – being able to analyse data that’s been contributed to create new products.
  • Cost saving synergy – ability to reduce costs for using the same data multiple times instead of having to reconnect it.
  • Network synergy – being able to use the network for one product or use case and use it to launch another product or use case

 

The holdup problem

A number of consortia think about what parts of their systems are going to be open source? What parts can be proprietary and can be charged for use and how do you balance these elements?

At the beginning of a business partnership one or both parties usually have to make a number of relationship specific investments such as purchasing software, implement it and adapt the necessary business processes. And this software and the business processes are not going to be usable anywhere else. The risk of course is if one party leaves the business partnership all of these tools and processes may become worthless. This is what the Prysm Group calls relationship specific investments.

The holdup problem occurs when a party doesn’t wish to enter a profitable business partnership with another party due to the risk that if it goes badly they’re going to lose the relationship specific investment.

The advantage blockchain can bring is that it reduces the risk of the holdup problem. In a data sharing use case or a data sharing consortium, nodes or validators have their own up to date copies of the ledgers.

To reduce the risk of relationship specific investment it is advised to structure IP and interoperability in a manner that if a member of a consortium leaves it they can still access and read the data. One of the best ways to doing that is to open source the data formats.

 

Monetisation

With many blockchain founding members eager to demonstrate an ROI on their blockchain investment, how critical is it to distinguish between short-term and the long-term monetization?

Stephanie notes that often after a new consortium has made its inaugural launch it wants to demonstrate short term revenues by sometimes charging a significant amount of money for these services. There is of course a short term / long term trade off. If the initial charge is too high at the beginning, a stage where the value of the network hasn’t necessarily been proven, it can impede adoption and thus long-term growth.

Stephanie recommends finding the right amount to set up for early monetisation in a manner that doesn’t inhibit maximum long-term adoption and network effects.

When thinking of monetisation models, especially early on, you have to be really thoughtful about who is getting value from the different products, that the consortium offers, and basing your monetisation model on that willingness to pay. An analysis also has to be made on, what are the costs and benefits that the different types of stakeholders are getting? And what is their outside option for not participating?

 

 

Spread the love

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *